-
FABIAN SOCIETY
British reformist “socialist” (social democratic)
organization founded in 1884. “It was named after the Roman general Quintus Fabius Maximus who
earned the nickname Cunctator (the Delayer) for his dilatory tactics and avoidance of a
decisive encounter with Hannibal. Its members were chiefly bourgeois intellectuals, scientists,
writers and politicians (the Webbs, Ramsay MacDonald, George
Bernard Shaw and others). The Fabians rejected the need for the workers to wage the class
struggle and rejected the socialist revolution, maintaining that transition from capitalism to
socialism could be effected by petty reforms and gradual social evolution. Lenin called Fabianism
‘an extremely opportunist trend’ [LCW 13:358]. In 1900 the Fabian Society formed a part of the
Labour Party. ‘Fabian socialism’ is a source of the Labour Party’s [original] ideology.” [Note 62
from LCW 28:502.]
FACEBOOK
See: PANOPTICON
FACIAL RECOGNITION SOFTWARE
“During 2018, the database of the facial-recognition app Clearview AI grew to a billion faces from 20 million.” —“Your Face Is Not Your Own”, New York Times Magazine, March 21, 2021.
FACT/FACTS
See: “ALTERNATIVE FACTS”,
ISOLATED FACTS
FACTIONS — Within the Proletarian Party
From the law of dialectics, that one divides into two, it is
obvious that there will always be factions within every political party or organization (unless,
possibly, the “party” is really a cult, with one guru who does all
the thinking, and with a bunch of blind and mindless followers). The question is what the
attitude of revolutionary communists should be towards factions. Should they be allowed, or
should efforts be made to suppress them?
In most Marxist-Leninist parties over the past
century there has been great hostility towards factions and factionalism, and very often members
accused of factionalism have been expelled. If the factionalists were truly disruptive of the
mass work of the party, then this was justified. But otherwise it was not. Although the party,
as a voluntary organization, may make whatever rules it wishes on such matters, still, it is
in the long-term interests of the party and the revolution to be internally democratic, to allow
differing views and even factions with similar minority views. After all, this minority may
eventually be proven correct! (This happened with Mao in the early Communist Party of China,
for example. Would it have been a good thing if Mao had been expelled from the CCP for
factionalism while the erroneous Ch’en Tu-hsiu and Wang Ming lines were in charge? Obviously
not!)
Factions within a revolutionary party
should be allowed, and definitely not suppressed, providing that:
1) The members of the faction, and the faction
as a whole, fully obey party discipline, and sincerely try to do the work the party assigns
them;
2) It does not obstruct the work of the party
among the masses; and
3) It is open and above board (not secret).
See also: “On the Question of Multiple
Revolutionary Parties”, by Scott H., at:
https://www.massline.org/Politics/ScottH/MultPart.htm, especially the last section.
“A faction is an organization within a party, united, not by its place of work, language or other objective conditions, but by a particular platform of views on party questions.... Every faction is convinced that its platform and its policy are the best means of abolishing factions, for no one regards the existence of factions as ideal. The only difference is that factions with clear, consistent, integral platforms openly defend their platforms, while unprincipled factions hide behind cheap shouts about their virtue, about their non-factionalism.” —Lenin, “The New Faction of Conciliators, Or the Virtuous” (Oct 18 [31], 1911), LCW 17:265, online at: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1911/oct/18b.htm
“Within the working class there is no basis for fierce conflict. Within the working class under the dictatorship of the proletariat, there is even less reason for splitting into two factional groups.” —Mao, Renmin Ribao [People’s Daily], Sept. 14, 1967. (Quoted in Peter R. Moody, Opposition and Dissent in Contemporary China (Hoover Institution: 1977), p. 47.) [Mao is here opposing the sort of factionalism within a proletarian party that leads to the functional inability to decide upon and implement a unified political line (through the mechanisms of democratic centralism). In other words, he is against the sorts of factions that really amount to having multiple mutually-opposed proletarian parties. —Ed.
“Outside a party there exist other parties and inside a party there exist factions; this has always been the case.” —Mao, quoted in “Make a Class Analysis of Factionalism”, by Hongqi Commentator, Peking Review, #19, May 10, 1968, p. 3.
“In order to unite the whole Party and the whole people it is necessary to
promote democracy and let the people speak out. It should be so within the Party; it should
also be so outside the Party…. All leading members within the Party must promote democracy
and let people speak out. What are the limits? One is that we must observe Party discipline,
the minority must obey the majority, and the whole party should obey the Center.
“Another limit is the prohibition on
organizing secret factions. We are not afraid of open opposition groups. Such people [i.e.,
those in secret factions] do not speak the truth to your face; what they say to your face
is all falsehood and deceit. They do not express their real aims. But as long as they do
not break discipline, as long as they are not carrying on any secret factional activities,
we should always allow them to speak and even if they should say the wrong things we should
not punish them. If people say the wrong things they can be criticized, but we should use
reason to convince them. What should we do if we [try to] persuade them and they are not
convinced? We can let them reserve their opinions. As long as they obey resolutions and
obey decisions taken by the majority, the minority can be allowed to reserve their various
opinions. Both within and outside the Party there is advantage in allowing the minority to
reserve their opinions. If they have incorrect opinions they can reserve them temporarily
and they will change their minds in the future. Very often the ideas of the minority will
prove to be correct. History abounds with such instances. In the beginning truth is not in
the hands of the majority of people, but in the hands of a minority. Marx and Engels held
the truth in their hands, but in the beginning they were in the minority. Lenin for a very
long period was also in the minority. We had this kind of experience within our own Party.
Both under the rule of Ch’en Tu-hsiu and during the period of rule of the ‘Left-wing’ Line
truth was not in the hands of the majority in the leading organs, but rather in the hands
of the minority.” —Mao, “On Democratic Centralism”, excerpt from his “Talk at an Enlarged
Central Work Conference” [informally known as the “Seven Thousand Cadres Conference”]
(Jan. 30, 1962); in Stuart Schram, ed., Chairman Mao Talks to the People: Talks and
Letters: 1956-1971, (NY: Pantheon/Random House, 1974), pp. 182-3.
[Mao explicitly supported the right
of Party members to form factions. At that same Conference, a few days after Mao’s comments
quoted above, Deng Xiaoping said in his speech that it is impermissible to form factions
in the Party. But Mao interrupted him to say that only secret factions were
unacceptable. See: Roderick MacFarquhar, The Origins of the Cultural Revolution—3: The
Coming of the Cataclysm 1961-1966, (Oxford University Press and Columbia University
Press, 1997), p. 174.]
FACTORYLESS GOODS PRODUCTION
A recent term which has arisen for the type of production fragmentation wherein a corporation
which supposedly “creates” and sells some commodities also entirely outsources the actual
physical production of those commodities to other companies, often in other, low-wage countries.
The “factoryless” corporation retains ownership of the intellectual property (patents, designs,
trademarks, copyrights, etc.) and the control of sales to customers, but itself does not
physically make anything!
“Factoryless goods production” represents a new
stage in two powerful trends in modern capitalism in the imperialist era: 1) The outsourcing of
more and more of a corporation’s once internal functions to other specialist companies; and 2) The
further financialization of the economy. Both of these trends are evidence of the ever-growing
parasitism within modern capitalism in the imperialist era. In some cases, especially those
involving complex technical commodities like computers and cell phones, the factoryless goods
producer may actually employ some engineers and overseers to supervise the physical production in
the outsourced factory in order to make sure its standards are met. Apple Computer does this, for
example, in its outsourced production plants in China. But it is still basically true that Apple,
and a growing number of other well-known and highly profitable companies, do not actually make
most of the things that they sell and which have their names on them.
FADS — In Science
See: SCIENCE FADS
FAILURE TO SPEAK OUT
Not speaking out when you should; such as when you have useful ideas or input to add, or valid
criticisms to make, but when you fear offending people or lack the necessary self-confidence to
put forward your own ideas or criticisms. As Mao pointed out, such failures reflect a tacit
indifference to the welfare of the people and are a form of what he called
“liberalism”, which we must train ourselves not to
succumb to.
“As we must account for every idle word, so must we account for every idle silence.” —Benjamin Franklin
FAITH
Having trust in a person, organization, or institution, or in their truthfulness or reliability.
Or having trust or belief in a doctrine, ideology, worldview, methodology, or the like. There may be
good and rational reasons for such faith in some cases, or perhaps no such rational reasons whatsoever
in other cases. Thus there are two main opposed types of faith: 1) reasonable and rational faith (or
trust) in someone or something based on good and solid evidence, long experience, and sound reasoning;
and 2) completely irrational, anti-scientific, or even absurdly foolish faith based on no good evidence
or logic at all. Sometimes individuals even have faith in imagined entities or in doctrines which are
so bizarre that more reasonable people are forced to judge them as having some form of serious mental
imbalance. For example, there are some people who believe that they themselves are Jesus or Napoleon or
some other historical personage! However, various forms of ordinary religious
faith are probably the most common types of major irrational faith.
“Faith: the War between Science and Religion
“It’s time we had a little talk. The New
York Times published an op-ed by Paul Davies (Nov. 24, 2007) that adresses the question: ‘Is
embracing the laws of nature so different from religious belief?’ Davies concludes that, ‘until
science comes up with a testable theory of the laws of the universe its claim to be free of faith is
manifestly bogus.’ Davies has confused two meanings of the word faith. The Oxford Concise
English Dictionary on my desk gives the two distinct meanings for faith as: ‘1) complete trust
or confidence, and 2) strong belief in a religion based on spiritual conviction rather than proof.’
A scientist’s ‘faith’ is built on experimental proof. The two meanings of the word faith,
therefore, are not only different, they are exact opposites.” —Robert L. Park, a professor
of physics at the University of Maryland, in his article “Two Meanings of ‘Faith’ Confuse Even
Scientists”, Skeptical Inquirer, Vol. 32, issue 1, March-April 2008, p. 14.
FAKE ENCOUNTER
Attacks on, and the cold-blooded murder of, revolutionaries under the false pretense that
a battle between the two sides had occurred. This sort of death squad murder of
revolutionaries happens in many countries, but the term arose in India where this has been
especially common in recent decades.
FAKE NEWS
Donald Trump, the notorious U.S.
demagogue former president, has constantly promoted the idea
that any news reports that he disagrees with, or that criticize him in any way (or which he
finds otherwise inconvenient), are “fake news”. In response, liberal opponents of Trump, as
well as the establishment media in general, have ridiculed Trump and have defended the
general reliability and trustworthiness of the news which they purvey. It’s an ironic
situation because most of what Trump calls “fake news” is in fact truthful, while the news
media nevertheless is essentially a purveyor of actual fake news on many important topics!
The news media in a capitalist-imperialist
country like the United States almost exclusively presents the viewpoint of the tiny ruling
class. It twists and systematically puts a bourgeois spin on virtually every news story of
a political nature. And, as John Pilger points out at length in his book Freedom Next
Time (2007), it fails to report much of the news which would embarrass the ruling
class or reflect poorly on it (such as most of its constant murders of innocent people
around the world). The “news”, as the capitalist ruling class calls it, is indeed largely
fake. The masses must come to understand this. But at the same time, we should not
accept the lies and also fake news that demagogues like Trump and other politicians
want to push down our throats.
See also:
DISINFORMATION
“What Donald Trump wants is more bias, not less; more fake news, not less. What he demands from the media is not objectivity, but complicity.” —David Frum, Trumpocracy: The Corruption of the American Republic (2017). [Frum is a conservative Republican author, but one who is alarmed by and opposed to Donald Trump. —Ed.]
FALLIBILITY
See:
INTELLECTUAL HUMILITY
FALLING RATE OF PROFIT
The claim or idea that within the capitalist mode of production there is in general, or overall,
a falling rate of profit over time. The classical bourgeois economists, including Adam Smith and
David Ricardo, assumed this to be true, as did Marx (at least in many of his writings). But
interestingly enough, this claim has never been established beyond all doubt even empirically,
let alone theoretically! Moreover, the importance of any actual overall long-term fall in the
rate of profit—even if it really does occur—has also by no means been demonstrated. In particular,
there are very good reasons for rejecting any such hypothesized long term tendency for the rate
of profit to fall as being the primary or ultimate cause of capitalist economic crises. [See the
entries below.]
FALLING RATE OF PROFIT THEORY (For Capitalist Economic Crises)
[To be added... ]
See also below, and:
OKISHIO THEOREM,
“ORGANIZED CAPITALISM”,
PROFITS—Corporate
The primary and leading textbook of genuine (revolutionary!) Marxism in the
late 19th century was Engels’s great work, Anti-Dühring (1878). Engels put tremendous
effort into writing this book, not only to refute the mostly pseudo-scientific theories and outlook
of Dühring, but also to summarize the whole revolutionary theory that Marx and he had
created. Marx read the entire manuscript before its publication, and even contributed a chapter
to the book, so we can be quite sure that there was nothing of major importance in the book that
Marx disagreed with, and no major omissions of central points that Marx himself wanted to include
in that definitive summation of their joint work.
Thus given the obvious care and importance
that both Engels and Marx put into this text, what was the theory of capitalist economic
crises that appeared in it? The very interesting thing is that what many academic Marxists
now take to be the central Marxist theory of crises, the falling rate of profit theory, is not
even mentioned! Instead, Engels sums up Marx’s crisis theory by first talking for several pages
about the anarchy and lack of overall planning which reigns in capitalist production [MECW
25:259-262] and then says:
“We have seen that the ever increasing
perfectibility of modern machinery is, by the anarchy of social production, turned into a
compulsory law that forces the individual industrial capitalist always to improved his machinery,
always to increase its productive force. The bare possibility of extending the field of production
is transformed for him into a similar compulsory law. The enormous expansive force of modern
industry, compared with which that of gases is mere child’s play, appears to us now as a
necessity for expansion, both qualitative and quantitative, that laughs at all resistance.
Such resistance is offered by consumption, by sales, by the markets for the products of modern
industry. But the capacity for extension, extensive and intensive, of the markets is primarily
governed by quite different laws that work much less energetically. The extension of the markets
cannot keep pace with the extension of production. The collision becomes inevitable, and as this
cannot produce any real solution so long as it does not break in pieces the capitalist mode of
production, the collisions become periodic. Capitalist production has begotten another ‘vicious
circle’.” [MECW 25:262-3]
This entire section of Anti-Dühring
thus focuses on two really major problems in capitalist production, first, its anarchic and
uncoordinated overall system of production, and second, its complete inability to expand its market
for the commodities it produces as fast as it expands that production—which leads to periodic
overproduction crises. No reference at all is made to any falling rate of profit.
However, did Marx change his mind, and his
crisis theory later? No he didn’t! Marx’s writing on the falling rate of profit, which Engels later
incorporated into the published version of Volume III of Capital, was done during the years
1863-1865, before Anti-Dühring was written in 1876-1878. This is further evidence
in support of the view of Michael Heinrich that Marx had after the mid-1860s in effect abandoned the
falling rate of profit theory of capitalist crises. (See: “Capital after MEGA: Discontinuities,
Interruptions, and New Beginnings”, by Michael Heinrich, Crisis & Critique journal, Vol. 3, #3,
2016(?), available online at:
https://www.bannedthought.net/MLM-Theory/PoliticalEconomyOfCapitalism/Crises/CapitalAfterMEGA-Discontinuities-Heinrich-2016-OCR.pdf )
FALLING RATE OF PROFIT THEORY — Empirical Investigations
Although the empirical data for the rate of profit in the United States and other countries is by
no means perfect, in part because it is not generally precisely calculated in terms of Marxist
categories of surplus value, constant capital, variable capital, and so forth, we do now have some
reasonable estimates which are good enough for us to draw some conclusions about the theory that
there is a long-term tendency for the rate of profit to fall, and the theory that capitalist
overproduction crises are caused by preceeding episodes of the falling rate of profit. The empirical
evidence, at least for the U.S., seems to rather conclusively show that both theories are simply not
correct.
The graph at the right shows the variations in the
rate of profit in the U.S. over one of the longest study periods available, from 1869 to 2010. (We
will further discuss some more in a moment why it is very important to have at least approximate
data from over very long periods.) [This graph is taken from Ivan D. Trofimov,
“The secular decline in profit rates: Time series analysis of a classical hypothesis”, 8 June 2018,
Munich Personal RePEc Archive]
You will first notice that in the graph there is no
overall long-term tendency for the rate of profit to decline. However, there are several periods of
sharply declining rates of profit and also several periods of sharply increasing rates of profit.
Starting from the left edge of the graph, for the post-Civil War years of 1869-1881, there was a
rapid rise in the annual profit rate from the 20% range to around 30%. But then, starting around
1882 and continuing until about 1891 there was a major sharp decline in the rate of profit. What
was going on then? This was a prolonged period of weakness in the American economy which at the time
came to be called the “Great Depression”. (This name for that period was later forgotten when the
even worse “Great Depression of the 1930s” came along.) But note that this major decline in profits
in the 1880s and beyond from around the 30% level all the way down to a low of just 9%, was
coextensive with that prolonged period of serious economic weakness. In other words, there is better
reason to say this period of declining profits was a consequence of the depression than there
is to say that declining profits led to that prolonged depression.
There was a recovery in the profit rate from around
10% in 1892 up to about 17% in 1905, followed by a relapse to back around 10% in 1911. Then, during
the period from 1911 to 1929, average profit rates turned around and began to significantly
rise again, from around just 10% annually up to around 15%. And note that this is the period
leading up to the beginning of the Great Depression
of the 1930s. So once again, during this important 18-year period, the hypothesis that falling
rates of profit led to that greatest of all U.S. and world overproduction crises so far is
shown to be completely false.
However, starting in 1929, when the Depression
began, until the worst depths of the Depression in 1933, the rate of profit dropped like a rock
almost all the way down to 0%. Again, this shows the fall in profit rates to be the result
of the capitalist overproduction crisis, not the cause of it.
After 1933 profit rates started to recover, and
then with government preparations for World War II, and the vast government spending during the war,
the profit rate zoomed up to its greatest level ever, to a peak of about 33%. At that level the
government was simply dumping money into the laps of corporations. Of course that couldn’t continue
after the war was over, at least not at that extreme level. So profits then fell considerably, down
to the low 20s percent by 1953 and then down to about 18% around 1959, even though the
quarter-century after WW2 was a major capitalist boom
period. In other words, the very big fall in profit rates from utterly fantastic down to merely
pretty damned good, in no way interrupted that post-World War II boom.
In the mid-1960s there was another short-term rise in
the rate of profits during the Vietnam War, up to a peak of about 23%. After that time, for a number
of decades, and until the severe Great Recession of 2008-9 and
its aftermath, the overall average profit rate continued wobbling within the fairly narrow range of
13% to 20%, even though the period of the Long Slowdown in the
growth rate of GDP began in 1973. In other words, although economic growth was cut in half for
decades on end, profit rates remained fairly stable.
Those modern proponents of the falling rate of
profits theory for capitalist crises almost always use statistics only from the late 1940s on. The
reason is pretty clear: If you start from that exceptional apex of a 33% profit rate during World War
II, or even from just a few years later, then everything might appear to be down hill from there on!
This is an example of why we argue that a fair assessment of the falling rate of profit theory should
be as long term as possible so that the statistical data cannot be distorted in this way.
We should note that the graphs of average profit
rates over time look very different in different countries. And a few countries, most notably Britain,
do in fact show a long term trend, more or less steady, in the decline of profit rates, for decade
after decade. This can probably be best explained by pointing out the particularities of Britain, and
especially its long decline as an imperial power, becoming ever less able to extract super-profits
from other countries.
The first serious empirical study of the
thesis that the rate of profit has a tendency to fall over time is that by Joseph M. Gillman in
1958. Although his methods and statistics have since been criticized (as, indeed, have those of
probably all other such studies!), we quote some of his results below. We also quote below a few
summaries or conclusions by other more recent studies which also pretty much disprove the basic
notions that there is a tendency for the rate of profit to fall over time, and that such a fall
can in any way explain the development of capitalist overproduction crises. The summary of one
study we quote claims to find “weak evidence” for the long-term tendency for the rate of profit to
decline. But we should note that that study also only starts with data from 1948, and doesn’t even
mention the contrary evidence from earlier decades. —S.H. [April 3, 2023]
See also:
PROFITS—U.S. Corporate Profits
“Marx developed his economic doctrines largely on the basis of axioms and
their demonstration mostly on the basis of purely hypothetical data. This was especially
true with respect to his law of the falling tendency of the rate of profit, although his
pages abound with numerous factual and historical references....
“Marx did not have the facts against
which to test his law of the falling tendency of the rate of profit. They first had to
emerge from generations of capitalist production. But we now have a considerable accumulation
of such facts, and it seems high time that, with Francis Bacon, we counted the horse’s
teeth instead of continuing to speculate about their number. True, the available statistics
are not in the form exactly suited to the purpose. Capitalist business firms do not report,
nor do official statistical agencies process their statistics to conform to the Marxist
categories. Above all, these statistics do not allow us to separate out the factors which
affect its realization, as a full test of the law as Marx formulated it would require. But
with this precaution in mind, they can be made to serve as fair appoximations for testing
the assumptions which underlie this law. [p. 31] ...
[Speaking with regard to the theory of
the rising organic composition of capital, the assumed general stability of the rate of
exploitation, and the supposed consequent falling rate of profits:] “Now we find that, while
for the measurable years before the early part of the twentieth century these theses are
fairly well sustained by the available statistical evidence, since that time, as measured
by an extension of the same evidence, they appear no longer to hold true.
“Had our investigations stopped with
1919, the case for Marx’s law would have been complete: a rising organic composition of
capital; a stabilizing tendency of the rate of surplus-value; a falling rate of profit,
corresponding inversely with a rising organic composition!
“But what of the years beginning with
1919? What has happened since then that seems to have abrogated that law? Since 1919 the
ratio c/v has tended to remain constant or even to fall. The rate of surplus-value,
if anything, has tended to rise, in spurts. And the rate of profit, rather than fall, has
tended to rise.” [p.59]
—Joseph M. Gillman, The Falling
Rate of Profit: Marx’s Law and its Significance to Twentieth-Century Capitalism, (NY:
Cameron Associates, 1958), excerpts from pages 31 & 59. [Gillman then attempts to “reformulate”
the theory of the tendency for the rate of profit to fall to account for developments in the
20th century. However, it seems to me that a “law” which doesn’t work for decades at a time
(including for a large part of the capitalist-imperialist era in the U.S.) is not much of a
law, not even much of a “tendential law”.
And note especially that the very worst economic crisis in U.S. history (so far), the Great
Depression of the 1930s, began following a nearly two-decade period when the rate of profit
was rising instead of falling (though of course it fell greatly in 1929 once the
financial crisis and Depression started). For this reason it seems completely unreasonable
to claim that the falling rate of profit in any way “led to” or “caused” or somehow “explains”
the Great Depression. —S.H.]
“The law of the tendential fall in the rate of profit has been at the center of theoretical and empirical debates within Marxian political economy since the publication of volume III of Capital. An important limitation of this literature is the relative paucity of modern econometric investigations of the behavior of the rate of profit. The central objective of this paper is to remedy this lacuna. We investigate the properties of the profit rate series utilizing the methods of time series econometrics. The evidence suggests that the rate of profit is non-stationary. We also specify a test of Marx’s law of the tendential fall in the rate of profit with a novel econometric model that explicitly accounts for the counter-tendencies and their time series properties. We find weak evidence of a long-run downward trend in the general profit rate for the U.S. economy for the period 1948-2007.” Abstract of the article by Deepankar Basu and Panayiotis T. Manolakos, “Is There a Tendency for the Rate of Profit to Fall? Econometric Evidence for the U.S. Economy, 1948-2007”, Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 45, Issue 1, May 24, 2012. The working draft of the paper, which makes stronger pro-falling-rate claims which were eased away from in the final publication, is online at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1098&context=econ_workingpaper
FALLING WAGES
See: WAGES—Falling
FALLOUT [From Nuclear Weapons]
“A 1999 National Cancer Institute study estimated that [radioactive] iodine in atom bomb explosions in Nevada from 1951 to 1962 caused thyroid cancer in up to 212,000 U.S. children born in the 1950s and 1960s.” —Joseph J. Mangano, “Japan Study Finds Rise in Cancer, Officials Deny Link to Fukushima”, The Washington Spectator [a liberal publication], June 1, 2018, p. 1.
FALSIFICATION PRINCIPLE
The dogma originated by the reactionary positivist philosopher Karl
Popper that no scientific theory can ever be completely verified and fully proven to be
correct and that, therefore, real scientific theories are those which could conceivably be
“falsified” but which have so far not been falsified or disproved by counter-evidence.
But what about the theory that the Earth goes
around the Sun? Hasn’t that been completely verified? Of course it has! [See:
Scott H., “Do we know for certain that the Earth goes around the Sun?” (1997), online
at:
https://www.massline.org/Philosophy/ScottH/certain.htm] So right away it is quite
clear that Popper’s claim that it is “impossible” to verify any scientific theory is
complete nonsense. Counter examples abound! But foolish academic philosophers commonly have
this irresistible compulsion to be totally oblivious to the obvious when that goes against the
supposedly “profound” doctrines they have cooked up.
However, Popper’s doctrine of “falsifiability”
has lots of other problems as well. It is itself a theory, and supposedly a scientific theory,
and therefore it applies to itself. This means that if it is true, we can never verify that it
is true! A more basic problem with it is that it fails to recognize that facts are only facts
in terms of a theory. (Or, putting it another way, there is no hard line between a fact and a
theory.) Therefore to adduce “facts” which falsify one theory is really to implicitly apply
another theory. But how (on Popper’s premises) do you know that theory is true?! Moreover,
this falsification doctrine is unidimensional, neglecting many other characteristics a
scientific theory must possess—such as internal coherence and compatibility with other
(especially broader) theories.
In short, Popper’s falsification dogma, as the
test of a theory as being scientific, is quite wrong, and easily demonstrated to be wrong.
Even most bourgeois philosophers have rejected it as simplistic at best, though in the sciences
today (especially physics) it is still generally accepted as some kind of gospel.
To falsify one theory is to verify its contrary.
For this reason “falsification” is merely another form of verification. But Popper was opposed
to the idea that anything could be verified because he was a Kantian-style
epistemological agnostic, and thus a promoter of the same
sorts of metaphysical obscurantism that he professed to abhor.
FALUN GONG
A religious, quasi-Buddhist, somewhat fanatical cult which began in China and which has spread
among the Chinese diaspora worldwide. It was founded in 1992 by Li Hongzhi, then a government
grain procurement clerk in northeastern China.
When the capitalist
roaders overthrew socialism after the death of Mao Zedong in 1976 and launched their continuing
and intensifying ideological campaign against Marxist-Leninist-Maoist ideology and the once general
mass concern for the welfare of other people, many individuals in China suddenly became morally and
ideologically adrift. And many of them turned toward one or another type of religion as “something
to believe in”. This is part of the explanation for why Falun Gong suddenly mushroomed into a major
religion in China in the 1990s. However, the new Chinese bourgeois ruling class looked with alarm
at the growth of this competing ideology to their own, and began to crack down on Falun Gong and
tried to suppress it. While this has reduced its affiliations in China by more than 90%, many of
its ideologues then left China and began to establish this cult in other countries including the
U.S. and Europe. While always a reactionary sect, Falun Gong has become ferociously anti-Communist,
in part because they identify “Communism” with their bitter enemy, the actually fascist ideology of
the national bourgeois ruling class in contemporary China.
FAMILY
Family relationships have been modified down through the course of human history by many factors, and
especially by whichever form of socioeconomic system is dominant at the time. And capitalism, like
other forms of exploitative class society such as slavery and feudalism, has had a severe and
ever-growing negative impact on human families. One major trend at the present time which should be
mentioned is the apparent gradual dying out of marriage altogether! (See:
MARRIAGE—Trends in Contemporary Capitalist Society)
Families have also been seriously harmed since World
War II by the increasing economic necessity for both parents (where there are two in the family)
to have jobs, which very negatively impacts the care and development of children. And the current
intensified gradual disappearance of more and more jobs, due to automation and artificial intelligence
as well as to the developing economic crisis, and the resulting increased poverty of more and more
people, is leading to further disintegration of the family structure. Similarly, we should mention the
virtual disappearance of the economically unified multi-generational extended family, including
grandparents, living in a single home. Instead, in modern capitalist society old people are largely
displaced from their families and (if their children can afford it) they are sent off to wither away
and die in what are often lonely and miserable conditions in commercial-profit old folks homes.
See also the entries below.
“The bourgeoisie has torn away from the family its sentimental veil, and has thus reduced the family relation to a mere money relation.” —Marx & Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848), Ch. I: MECW 6:487.
FAMILY DISCORD
As noted in the above entry, capitalism has had a severe and disruptive effect on families. One of
the relatively underappreciated results of current capitalist trends, and the long-developing new
capitalist overproduction crisis which began around 1973,
in particular, is the increasing level of discord, personal, political and social antagonisms, and
such, within families too, as well as society at large.
“What’s Ripping American Families Apart?
“At least 27 percent of Americans are
estranged from a member of their own family, and research suggests about 40 percent of Americans
have experienced estrangement at some point.
“The most common form of estrangement is
between adult children and one or both parents—a cut usually initiated by the child....
“Some kids seem to think they need to cut
off their parents just to have their own life.... In other cases, children may be blaming their
parents for the fact that they are not succeeding as they had hoped—it’s Mom and Dad who
screwed me up.
“I write about this phenomenon here because
it feels like a piece of what seems to be the psychological unraveling of America, which has
become an emerging theme of this column. Terrible trends are everywhere. Major depression rates
among youths aged 12 to 17 rose by almost 63 percent between 2013 and 2016. American suicide
rates increased by 33 percent between 1999 and 2019. The percentage of Americans who say they
have no close friends has quadrupled since 1990, according to the Survey Center on American
Life. Fifty-four percent of Americans report sometimes or always feeling that no one knows them
well, according to a 2018 Ipsos survey.
“I confess, I don’t understand what’s
causing this. But social pain and vulnerability are affecting everything: our families, schools,
politics and even our sports.
“A friend notes that politics has begun to
feel like an arena where many people can process and regulate their emotional turmoil indirectly.
Anxiety, depression and anger are hard to deal with within the tangled intimacy of family life.
But political tribalism becomes a mechanism with which people can shore themselves up, vanguish
shame, fight for righteousness and find a sense of belonging.”
—David Brooks, a bourgeois columnist,
New York Times, July 30, 2021. [Brooks may be puzzled by the causes of all the things he
points out, but to Marxists the answer is simple: bourgeois society is disintegrating.
That does mean worsening chaos and conflict, of course, and lots of people looking for easy
answers. But it also means there is hope that humanity can eventually come out of this capitalist
nightmare and build a new positive socialist, and then communist, existence for itself. —Ed.]
FAMILY INCOME
See: HOUSEHOLD INCOME
FAMINES
[To be added...]
See also below, and
GREAT LEAP FORWARD
FAMINES — Imperialist Caused
There have been a large number of famines around the world which were caused most fundamentally
by foreign imperialism, sometimes even on purpose (for genocidal reasons).
One of the worst of these famines was that
in British-ruled India in 1943-1945. This famine in Bengal and adjoining provinces killed well over
a million people and perhaps as many as 6 or 7 million. British Prime Minister Winston Churchill
ordered that India continue to export grain to England even as the famine developed in Bengal, and
later, at a time when the famine was quite severe, ordered that all shiploads of grain from Australia
by-pass India and bring it to England—not because it was needed there at the time, but just for
storage for possible future needs! [For more information about this particular famine see:
“The Forgotten Holocaust—The 1943/44 Bengal Famine”, by Dr. Gideon Polya (2005), at
http://globalavoidablemortality.blogspot.com/2005/07/forgotten-holocaust-194344-bengal.html ,
a BBC broadcast on the topic which included Dr. Polya and Economics Nobel Laureate Amartya
Sen at
http://www.open2.net/thingsweforgot/bengalfamine_programme.html, and the book Churchill’s
Secret War: The British Empire and the Ravaging of India during World War II, by Madhusree
Mukerjee (2010).]
See also the book by Mike Davis, Late Victorian
Holocausts (2002) which shows that the British response to two late 19th century famines amounted
to genocide, and notes that in some British labor camps people were fed fewer calories than even in
the Nazi death camps.
FANNIE MAE
A semi-official agency of the U.S. federal government engaged in issuing and guaranteeing home
mortgages. Its formal name is the Federal National Mortgage Association, but it is almost
universally referred to by its nickname “Fannie Mae”. Officially it is what is known as a
“government-sponsored enterprise” (GSE) which was set up by Congress to
support and stabilize the mortgage credit market, where mortgages and mortgage-related assets
(such as CDO’s and similar derivatives)
are bought and sold by financial capitalists. Fannie Mae is one of several officially independent
GSE’s, but is in reality a federal agency, which props up the mortgage portion of the financial
industry. It is one of the originators of the securitized
bundles of mortgages which have played such a major role in the current financial crisis.
Fannie Mae also purchases mortgage-related derivatives for its own account and issues its own
bonds to pay for them. It is, in other words, a key pillar of the financial house of cards that
constitutes the U.S. mortgage market.
Fannie Mae was first set up as a government
agency in the Great Depression of the 1930s. In 1968 it was re-chartered by Congress as a GSE,
but remained a quasi-official government agency because of its implicit government financial
guarantee. The financial panic of 2008 showed that its economic “independence” was a pure
fiction. In early September 2008, Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson announced the rescue package
for Fannie Mae and its cousin Freddie Mac, and the formal
takeover by the government of both companies.
“Fannie Mae is the nation’s largest mortgage buyer and a financial
juggernaut that affects the lives of tens of millions of home buyers. It was taken
over by the federal government on Sept. 8, 2008, along with Freddie Mac, as the two
mortgage giants struggled with deep losses and investors lost confidence in the pair.
“Many experts believe that Fannie
and Freddie are likely to remain wards of the state for years.
“And, given the alarm in some
quarters over the mounting budget deficit, these two giants and their vast obligations
are likely to remain conveniently—and controversially—off the federal books. Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac have obligations of $3.9 trillion to investors who bought bundles
of mortgages that the companies assembled.
“Lawmakers of both parties, eager
to demonstrate their scorn for the companies, have called for their eradication. But few
policy makers are willing to take aggressive steps that might weaken the housing market.
On Dec. 24, 2009, the White House quietly disclosed that it had, in effect, given the
companies a blank check by making their federal credit line unlimited; the ceiling had
been $400 billion.” —From the New York Times website.
FANON, Frantz (1925-1961)
An Afro-Caribbean psychiatrist, writer and revolutionary who was born on the island of Martinique,
but who spent most of his adult life in France and Algeria. He strongly supported the Algerian
War of Independence from France and was a member of the Algerian National Liberation Front. He
was a political radical who focused on anti-colonialism and the psychopathology of colonialism.
Although he was somewhat influenced by Marxism, in the revisionist and philosophical idealist
form that it often took in France, he was never really a revolutionary Marxist. He was more
influenced by Jean-Paul Sartre and French idealist philosophy as well as the radical psychiatrist
Jacques Lacan, and anti-colonial movements such as Négritude. His most famous and influential
book was The Wretched of the Earth, which was published just before his death. In that
work, and elsewhere, Fanon strongly defended the right of colonialized peoples to use whatever
violence was necessary in struggling for their freedom.
Fanon has been hugely influential within
anti-colonial movements around the world and also within academia, especially in the fields of
“critical theory” and academic intellectual “leftism”. Fanon’s own work and writings formed the
initial basis for the academic field of post-colonialism,
though he should not be held fully responsible for the extremely esoteric and largely
incomprehensible form that eventually took. It is quite unfortunate that this genuinely
revolutionary man, who was so justly outraged by the consequences of colonialism, is now often
upheld in contrast to, and in partial opposition to, revolutionary Marxism.
FANSHEN [Book]
A classic book, by William Hinton, about the course of
social revolution in the Chinese village of Long Bow in Lucheng County, Shansi Province. It
describes in careful detail the efforts, often successful, sometimes not so, of the local
members of the Communist Party of China to mobilize the masses in this village to make
revolution. It often demonstrates the leadership method of the mass
line in practice.
“Every revolution creates new words. The Chinese Revolution created a whole new vocabulary. A most important word in this vocabulary was fanshen. Literally, it means ‘to turn the body,’ or ‘to turn over.’ To China’s hundreds of millions of landless and land-poor peasants it meant to stand up, to throw off the landlord yoke, to gain land, stock, implements, and houses. But it meant much more than this. It meant to throw off superstition and study science, to abolish ‘word blindness’ and learn to read, to cease considering women as chattles and establish equality between the sexes, to do away with appointed village magistrates and replace them with elected councils. It meant to enter a new world. That is why this book is called Fanshen. It is the story of how the peasants of Long Bow Village built a new world.” —William Hinton, on the first page of his great book.
“This is a very important book for revolutionary communists to read. It is what first opened up my eyes as to what communists are trying to do, and how they are trying to go about doing it.” —Scott Harrison
FARADAY, Michael (1791-1867)
British physicist and chemist most famous for his investigations into electricity, and more
specifically the relationship between magnetic and electric fields. Faraday’s Law of Induction
(formulated in 1831) states that a changing magnetic field produces an electric field and
therefore a current in a wire. This is the basic principle behind the generation of modern
electricity networks. Faraday’s Law of Electrolysis (1833) states that during electrolysis the
amount of chemical change that the current produces is proportional to the amount of electricity
used, and that the amounts of chemical changes which occur through the use of the same quantity
of electricity are proportional to their equivalent weights (and therefore proportional to their
different atomic weights).
“Our physicists led lives in social worlds that covered the full middle-class range, from lower to upper, but rarely found themselves above or below those stations. By far the most prominent exception ... is Michael Faraday, born in a London slum.” —William H. Cropper, Great Physicists (2001).
FARC or FARC-EP
The Fuerzas Armadas Revolucionarias de Colombia—Ejército del Pueblo, or Revolutionary Armed
Forces of Colombia—People’s Army. A nominally Marxist guerrilla organization in Colombia which
has been engaged in war against the Colombian government for many decades. [More to be
added.]
See also:
WAR ON DRUGS
FARM WORKERS
[To be added...]
See also:
RURAL LABORER
FASCISM
The form of capitalist society in which the bourgeoisie rules by open, terroristic
violence against the people, as opposed to bourgeois
democracy. As an extreme form of bourgeois nationalist rule, fascism often also includes
rabid forms of racism, often to the point of genocide. The most vicious and notorious example
was Nazi Germany (1933-1945).
All capitalist countries have at least some
elements of fascism, to one degree or another, and to the extent that the bourgeoisie thinks
these elements are “necessary” in order to maintain their rule. Nevertheless, we call those
countries which allow relatively more freedoms of speech, of the press, of association, and
allow at least some mass protest bourgeois democracies, while those countries which
have few if any such freedoms we call fascist.
See also:
LUMPENPROLETARIAT AND FASCISM
“Fascism is the open terrorist dictatorship of the most reactionary,
most chauvinistic, most imperialist elements of finance capital.” —Statement of the
Enlarged Executive of the Communist International, Moscow, 1933.
[Although this is still a fairly
good capsule definition of fascism, it is based a little too much on the form fascism
took in Italy and then Nazi Germany during the 1930s. Fascism is best thought of as a
form of capitalist rule, and as such it may exist even in countries which are not
themselves imperialist ones or dominated by their own finance capitalists. —S.H.]
Principles in the MLM Conception of Fascism:
1. Fascism is one of the
two major forms of capitalist class rule, the other being bourgeois
democracy. Both fascism and bourgeois democracy are forms of the
dictatorship of the bourgeoisie.
But bourgeois democracy is a qualitatively more relaxed form of that dictatorship in
that it allows more scope for the working class and masses to express their opinions,
to protest, to organize themselves and for their organizations to operate openly
without being suppressed, and to publish and distribute newspapers and other political
literature. Bourgeois democracy also allows elections, but while we support the
existence of these elections, we also recognized that they are mostly rigged by the
bourgeoisie through their control of what they call “education” and their ownership
of nearly all the mass media.
2. Whether or not a regime
is fascist is primarily a question of how it goes about exercising its
dictatorship over other classes, and especially over the proletariat and masses.
3. How the regime treats
revolutionaries and revolutionary parties (along with the militant mass
movements they organize and lead) is especially key in determining whether a regime is
a fascist one or not. This is because it is revolutionaries who are actually most active
in making use of the rights of speaking out, protesting, assembling, organizing others,
and publishing writings promoting the real interests of the workers and masses.
4. Although terrorism
characterizes fascism, there is also plenty of terrorism directed at the “unruly masses”
by the ruling class under bourgeois democracy. It is not that terrorism against the
people only exists under fascism; it is just that it is qualitatively more extensive
and severe.
5. Fascism and bourgeois
democracy are theoretical extremes or archetypes; all actual capitalist regimes have
elements of both types of bourgeois rule. (With the possible exception of Nazi Germany
which really was close to the total fascist archetype!)
6. Regimes can be
categorized as either fascist or bourgeois democratic based on whether
they most closely approximate the fascist theoretical archtype or the bourgeois
democratic theoretical archetype.
7. Individual laws or
actions by the bourgeois state can be appropriately categorized as fascist if
they correspond to the sorts of laws or actions typical of the fascist theoretical
archetype, and whether or not they occur in a regime which we overall categorize as
fascist.
8. Since fascism vs.
bourgeois democracy is a matter of how the bourgeoisie rules, it is possible
for it to rule in different ways in different areas (as well as at different times),
and therefore to be a fascist regime in one area and a bourgeois democratic regime in
another area. Thus regions under martial law are under fascist conditions, and this is
also more apt to be the case within internal colonies and ghettos.
9. Bourgeois democracy
is unstable and periods of fascism are virtually inevitable—especially as the
bourgeoisie faces a major crisis or nears its overthrow.
10. Struggling against
fascist laws and policies of the government in a bourgeois democracy is a struggle for
reforms. We should never forget this nor confine our work mostly (or only!) to
the struggle for a purer form of bourgeois democracy; that would turn us from
communists into bourgeois democrats. But on the other hand, the struggle against
fascist laws and policies is an important and necessary part of building a
truly revolutionary struggle against capitalism in any of its forms.
Conclusion: Large areas
of the world are already appropriately called fascist from the proletarian
revolutionary point of view. Even in countries and areas where bourgeois democracy
still exists, there are often new fascist laws and policies being implemented, and
frequently there is at least a slow trend in the direction of fascism. As the world
capitalist economic crisis continues to intensify over the next decade and beyond
there will almost certainly be a further impetus toward fascism in a growing number
of countries. This is something we need to recognize, prepare for, and resist with
all our might.
—Adapted and summarized from a
more thorough discussion of fascism in the 19-page essay, “A Short Introduction to the
MLM Conception of Fascism”:
PDF
Version [335 KB];
MS Word
Version [122 KB]. —Scott Harrison
FASCISM — And National Chauvinism and Racism
Fascism, as the article above states, is in its central essence one of the two forms of the
rule of the capitalist class; namely, the form of that rule which involves the open terroristic
suppression of the working class and masses. However, it is also true that fascism, virtually
wherever it arises, is extremely national chauvinist and deeply
racist, often to the point of genocide. It is important to
understand just why this is.
First, all capitalist ruling classes are
based in one or another nation state, and they are a quite small part of the whole population
even in that one nation. For such a ruling class to cohere and continue to rule over its domain
it must develop strong internal ideologies of not only capitalist class cohesion but also
promote as many other forms and mechanisms of national unity as possible, including (normally)
ethnic and linguistic cohesion. The ruling class itself is tiny, the “one percent” as we now
say. So it is all the more important for them that they find and promote reasons beyond just
their own class interest, such as shared ethnicity, language and “race”, and often religion, to
try to unite the rest of the population in support of their rule.
That much is more or less true of all capitalist
countries at all times. However, in times of serious social crisis, whether that be major
capitalist economic crisis or war, it becomes even more pressing for the tiny ruling class to
use every means at its disposal to promote “national unity” (i.e., general unity in support of
itself as the only “legitimate” ruler of the nation).
Moreover, it becomes absolutely imperative in
times of social crisis for the ruling class to find someone else to blame for the hugely
intensifying problems and worsening condition of the broad masses. They absolutely need
scapegoats in order to keep the masses from turning against them, since their capitalist
class itself, and the capitalist-imperialist system, is the real cause of these economic, war,
environmental and other disasters. Of course the natural people for them to blame are: other
nations, and—within their own nation—those people who most strongly oppose their rule and the
people who are in some way different (because of race, ethnicity, religion, language, etc.)
from the largest part of the population.
Fascism is the form of bourgeois rule which
is necessary for the capitalist class in times of crisis, and, in turn, because it
develops in times of crisis it requires that the ruling class intensify its national
chauvinism, racism and hatred of other peoples, in order to maintain its continued rule. And
it is especially in times of crisis and when there is misery for growing sections of the
people that the ruling class must find someone else to blame, scapegoats, for the disasters
they and their system have created. They even find it necessary at times to whip up their
adherents into a frenzy and to physically attack and even murder their opponents and the
scapegoats they have identified. Fascism is indeed a horrible, despicable thing—the
capitalist-imperialist ruling class at their very worst.
FASCISM — Bourgeois Conceptions Of
The central characteristic of all bourgeois conceptions of fascism is that they do not
view either fascism or “democracy” (i.e., bourgeois democracy) as forms of rule by the
capitalist class. Instead they focus on secondary issues such as whether more than one
bourgeois party exists and is allowed to compete in “fair” elections.
“[Fascism is the system that] favors big business, strengthens the position of heavy industries, retains enough of the profit system to permit the elite to build personal fortunes... facilitates cartelization, and spends huge sums for military purposes [and in which] free collective bargaining and self-government of labor organizations is abolished.” —Legislative Reference Service of the Library of Congress, Fascism in Action: A Documented Study and Analysis of Fascism in Europe (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1947), p. 204; quoted in Robert W. McChesney and John Nichols, People Get Ready: The Fight Against a Jobless Economy and a Citizenless Democracy (2016), p, 180. [These things are of course generally true of fascism, but they are not the essence of it. —Ed.]
“But [after World War II] very quickly any momentum to directly
attack fascism disappeared, and all attention went to addressing the ‘communist’
threat. It was as if World War II had never happened. Anti-fascism was suspect, unless
the critic made it abundantly clear that communism was every bit as evil, as [U.S.
Congressman Wright] Patman did in his foreword to the 1947 fascism report. And
eventually anti-fascism just became suspect, period.” —Robert W. McChesney and John
Nichols, ibid.
[Anti-fascism is indeed highly
suspect to the capitalist ruling class, even to its bourgeois democratic proponents,
for several reasons: 1) Anti-fascism is most strongly and insistently promoted by
communists and revolutionaries; 2) Many people, and not just Marxists, do correctly
view fascism as an alternative form of capitalist rule (which deeply offends capitalist
supporters of bourgeois democracy); and 3) The bourgeoisie as a whole knows that it
is “forced” to implement some fascist measures from time to time even during periods of
overall bourgeois democracy, and it recognizes that more such measures or even outright
fascism may be “necessary” in the future in order to keep down the unruly working
class and masses during times of economic or social crisis. Therefore, the only way
that social democrats and
“progressives” can bring themselves to oppose trends
toward fascism is to themselves adopt, to a considerable degree, the wishy-washy
conception of fascism that is somewhat more acceptable to the ruling class:
i.e., the conception that fails to acknowledge that fascism is one of the two
forms of the dictatorship of the bourgeoisie. —Ed.]
FASCISM — Creeping
Fascism is not an “all or nothing” sort of thing. There can be, and usually are, fascist laws
and government actions even within the most “democratic” form of bourgeois
democracy. Moreover, the outright fascist form of bourgeois class dictatorship does not
normally arrive totally out of the blue; there are usually many smaller steps in that direction
before the one qualitative big step occurs. These smaller steps, and accumulating fascist laws
and actions, can be viewed as “creeping fascism”. The United States and most of the bourgeois
democratic countries of the world should now be viewed as being in a period of creeping
fascism.
See also the entry below on Trends Toward
Fascism within the U.S., and:
BLOCKING TRAFFIC
“As nightfall does not come at once, neither does oppression. In both instances, there is a twilight when everything remains seemingly unchanged.” —William O. Douglas, U.S. Supreme Court Justice, quoted in The Week, Jan. 17, 2020, p. 15.
FASCISM — Trends Toward Within the U.S.
“[A]lthough fascism is officially detested by nearly every American
since World War II, it is striking that so many of the developments associated with
fascism have become commonplace in the United States since 1945: massive government
spending on armaments and militarism; seemingly endless wars barely understood by most
Americans; growing inequality; massive monopolistic firms that dominate the economy far
more than in FDR’s era; weak and feeble news media that largely propagate elite opinion;
a governing system that is mostly if not entirely in the pocket of the wealthy; the
disappearing rule of law; and what seems like near ubiquitous and unaccountable
surveillance of private citizens. That’s a sobering list.”
—Robert W. McChesney & John
Nichols, People Get Ready: The Fight Against a Jobless Economy and a Citizenless
Democracy (2016), p. 40. [The authors are social-democratic reformers, and their
concept of “fascism” therefore tends to be more amorphous than that of MLM. Nevertheless
there is some real truth to their observations here. Note also that these observations
apply to the period before Donald Trump was elected president. As those on the
Left are now quite aware, Trump is already intensifying the existing long trend in the
direction of fascism in the U.S. —Ed.]
FAT SHAMING
The criticism or ridicule of a person for being fat. In rare cases it may be that being fat (or,
more politely, being overweight) is an unavoidable result of a physical health problem. However,
nearly all of the time in this contemporary American society, it is simply an indication of a
very unhealthy lifestyle in which people are eating too much, eating too much of the wrong sorts
of food, and/or are not getting enough physical exercise. Thus it seems to me that some criticism
of fat people may actually be appropriate, although ridicule should not normally be used. I say
this despite being someone who is a bit fat myself and thus deserving some criticism for that!
—S.H. [10/29/22]
See also:
OBESITY
“An American Airlines passenger demanded ‘reparations’ for having been ‘sandwiched between two obese humans’ for a three-hour flight. Passenger Sydney Watson, an Australian conservative commentator said she was ‘totally fine with being in the news for fat shaming.’” —The Week magazine, October 28, 2022, p. 6.
FATALISM
The view that one cannot choose between alternative actions, or that one’s choice is “predetermined”
(and hence not really genuine). Often confused with determinism.
See also:
COMPATIBILISM
FAVELA
Brazilian term for the horribly crowded and miserable slum districts in major cities that are
often constructed by the poor and homeless themselves out of whatever pieces of discarded
junk materials that are available. These slums are rapidly growing.
In 2000 there were approximately 6.5 million
people living in favelas in Brazil. In 2010, in just 10 years time, this number increased
to 11.4 million, despite Brazil’s strong economic growth in that period. In Rio de Janeiro
there are now about 1.4 million people living in these slums, or about 22% of the 6.3 million
residents of the city. The second largest concentration is in São Paulo, with nearly 1.3
million people living in favelas.
The picture at right shows one particularly sharp
boundary between the favelas and great wealth in Brazil.
FBI
See: FEDERAL BUREAU OF INVESTIGATION
FDI
See: FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT
Dictionary Home Page and Letter Index