SAINT-SIMON, Claude Henri de Rouvroy, comte de (1760-1825)
French utopian socialist.
SARTRE, Jean-Paul (1905-1980)
A prominent French bourgeois philosopher of existentialism,
who was also somewhat influenced by Marxism. [More to be added.]
See also:
Philosophical doggerel
about Sartre.
SAVIORS (Political)
[Intro material to be added... ]
[The second stanza of the American translation of the
Internationale:]
We want no condescending saviors
To rule us from their judgment hall,
We workers ask not for their favors
Let us consult for all:
To make the thief disgorge his booty
To free the spirit from its cell,
We must ourselves decide our duty,
We must decide, and do it well.
“For the bourgeois world, based upon the principles of these
philosophers [the utopian socialists], is quite as irrational and unjust, and,
therefore, finds its way to the dust-hole quite as readily as feudalism and all the
earlier stages of society. If pure reason and justice have not, hitherto, ruled the
world, this has been the case only because men have not rightly understood them.
What was wanted was the individual man of genius, who has now arisen and who
understands the truth. That he has now arisen, that the truth has now been clearly
understood, is not an inevitable event, following of necessity in the chain of
historical development, but a mere happy accident. He might just as well have been
born 500 years earlier, and might then have spared humanity 500 years of error,
strife, and suffering.
“This mode of outlook is
essentially that of all English and French and of the first German socialists,
including Weitling. Socialism is the expression of absolute truth, reason and
justice and has only to be discovered to conquer all the world by virtue of its
own power. And as absolute truth is independent of time, space, and of the
historical development of man, it is a mere accident when and where it is
discovered. With all this, absolute truth, reason, and justice are different with
the founder of each different school. And as each one’s special kind of absolute
truth, reason, and justice is again conditioned by his subjective understanding,
his conditions of existence, the measure of his knowledge and his intellectual
training, there is no other ending possible in this conflict of absolute truths
than that they shall be mutually exclusive one of the other.” —Engels,
Anti-Dühring (1878), MECW 25:20.
SAY, Jean-Baptiste (1767-1832)
French economist who systematized and vulgarized Adam Smith’s
theory. Almost exclusively known today for what later came to be known as his “principle”
or “Law” (see below).
“SAY’S LAW”
The simple-minded (and grossly incorrect) claim that capitalist production creates its
own demand (i.e. its own full demand), and consequently that there cannot possibly
be any “gluts” or overproduction. This so-called “law” is
one of the fundamental axioms of bourgeois economics, though it often goes unacknowledged.
[Further material to be added...]
“Say’s earth-shaking discovery [Marx is being ironic here!] that ‘commodities can only be bought with commodities’ simply means that money is itself the converted form of the commodity. It does not prove by any means that because I can buy only with commodities, I can buy with my commodity, or that my purchasing power is related to the quantity of commodities I produce.” —Marx, TSV, 3:119.
SCHOLASTICISM
[To be added...]
See also:
Philosophical doggerel
about Scholasticism.
SCHUMPETER, Joseph (1883-1946) [Pronounced: SHUM-PAY-ter]
Important Austrian bourgeois economist of the first half of the 20th century.
His father owned a textile factory, and not surprisingly Schumpeter found great virtues in
the capitalist system. He emphasized the importance of change under capitalism, and is
famous in bourgeois circles for his description of capitalism as “creative destruction”.
(Of course this is old news to us Marxists! In the Communist Manifesto Marx and
Engels say “The bourgeoisie cannot exist without constantly revolutionizing the instruments
of production, and thereby the relations of production, and with them the whole relations
of society.” [MECW 6:487.])
At a time when most bourgeois economists
denied that economic cycles should even exist, Schumpeter said there were actually three
different ones:
1) A very short-term inventory cycle (which he called the “Kitchin Cycle”, after another
bourgeois economist, Joseph Kitchin), and which lasted 3 to 4 years;
2) An approximately 10-year cycle, which is the industrial cycle that Marx focused on (but
which Schumpeter—loathe to give any credit to Marx—called “Juglar Cycles”, after a
minor French economist, Clément Juglar, who talked about them long after Marx did). These
cycles were erroneously explained by Schumpeter as being due to changes in investment
patterns; and
3) Schumpeter’s version of Kondratiev’s 45-year long-term
waves, which Schumpeter attributed to waves in invention and innovation.
None of his discussion of economic cycles
had much validity, but by bourgeois standards even to have recognized the existence
of any cycles or waves makes you seem rather smart these days!
One of Schumpeter’s students was
Paul Sweezy, the primary founder of the
Monthly Review school of Marxist political
economy. While Sweezy broke away from Schumpeter and bourgeois economics in many ways,
there is still more than a touch of his ideas that were carried over.
SCIENTIFIC LAW
A scientific law, or law of nature or society, is a statement of an order or relationship
between phenomena that so far as is known always holds true under the stated or implied
conditions. Thus, for example, the law of gravity is a statement about the mutual attraction
(and the strength of that attraction at various distances) between all presently known forms
of matter.
On rare occasions, mere tendencies or
probabilities are sometimes spoken of as laws, as with Marx’s discussion of what he calls
“the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall” (in Part 3 of Volume III of
Capital). But the modern practice is to describe such partial regularities not
as “laws”, but simply as “tendencies”. In the way the term is almost universally used in
science today there are never any exceptions to scientific laws. If exceptions to what was
previously thought to be a law are found, then either the scope of the application
of that law is narrowed to exclude such situations, or else (if that cannot be done) it is
no longer considered to be a law at all.
SECT (In politics)
In the non-pejorative sense, a sect is simply “a group adhering to a distinctive
doctrine or leader”. [Merriam Webster’s Collegiate Dictionary, 10th ed.]
However, the word ‘sect’ also carries with it the connotation of small size, and being
outside of the mainstream. Thus a revolutionary sect is a small group which is outside
the mainstream of the revolutionary movement. All new political parties either start off
as sects, or else form out of other parties or mass movements which themselves started out
as sects. There is nothing necessarily wrong about starting out small and different from
the mainstream; but it is foolish and self-defeating for any political group to
permanently remain just a sect, i.e. a small group unconnected to the masses and the mass
movement.
See also SECTARIAN
(below), and: CULT.
“The International was founded in order to replace the
socialist or semi-socialist sects by a real organization of the working class for
struggle. The original Rules and the Inaugural Address show this at a glance. On the
other hand, the International could not have asserted itself if the course of history
had not already smashed sectarianism. The development of socialist sectarianism
and that of the real labor movement always stand in indirect proportion to each
other. So long as the sects are justified (historically), the working class is not
yet ripe for an independent historical movement. As soon as it has attained this
maturity all sects are essentially reactionary....
“And the history of the
International was a continual struggle of the General Council against the
sects and attempts by amateurs to assert themselves within the International itself
against the real movement of the working class.” —Marx, Letter to Adolphe Hubert,
Aug. 10, 1871, MECW 44:252.
SECTARIAN (Adj.)
[Primary sense in Marxist politics:] 1. Having and promoting ideas which prevent
or obstruct a political group or party from connecting up with the masses and the mass
movement, and from transforming existing reformist mass struggle into revolutionary
mass struggle. (See also: mass perspective.)
[Secondary sense in Marxist politics:] 2. Being unwilling to work with individuals or
groups (other than your own) for some common purpose, or obstructing such cooperation and
“united fronts” through hostility and disrespect
towards those with ideas differing from your own.
SECULAR (Adj.)
[As commonly used in economics, esp. bourgeois economics:] Of or relating to a long
term trend. Example: A “secular decline in profits” means “a long trend of indefinite
duration in the decline of profits.” The term usually implies that there is some
unspecified (and perhaps unknown) force or cause which is behind the trend being
mentioned.
SEMANTICS
The branch of linguistics concerned with the meaning of words and sentences. The
sub-branch concerned with the meaning of words, specifically, is known as
lexical semantics. Scientific semantics should
not be confused with the bourgeois pseudo-scientific academic sect which goes by the
name of General Semantics.
SENECA, Lucius Annaeus (c. 4 BCE-65 CE)
Roman philosopher; one of the great representatives of
Stoicism.
SENIOR, Nassau William (1790-1864)
English vulgar economist and apologist for capitalism. Marx called him one of the
“economic spokesmen of the bourgeoisie”. He was strongly opposed to the shortening of the
work day which at that time was often 12 hours/day, or more!
SENSE DATA
The sensory qualities of things (colors, shapes, smells, etc.) which we supposedly
experience directly, without any rational interpretation, and without any consideration
of the physical objects which may be causing them. Empiricists
usually make “sense data” the foundation of their theory of knowledge, but doing so tends
to beg many questions.
See also:
QUALIA.
SERVE THE PEOPLE
[To be added... ]
See also:
PATERNALISM.
SERVICE (Political Economy)
“A service is nothing more than the useful effect of a use-value, be it of a commodity, or be it of labor.” —Marx, Capital, vol. I, ch. VII, sect. 2: (International, p. 192; Penguin, pp. 299-300.)
“In general, we may say that service is merely an expression for the particular use-value of labor where the latter is useful not as an article, but as an activity.” —Marx, Capital, vol. I: (Penguin, appendix, p. 1047. [Not included in the International edition])
“Where the direct exchange of money for labor takes place without the latter producing capital, where it is therefore not productive labor, it is bought as service, which in general is nothing but a term for the particular use-value which the labor provides, like any other commodity; it is however a specific term for the particular use-value of labor in so far as it does not render service in the form of a thing, but in the form of an activity, which however in no way distinguishes it for example from a machine, for instance a clock.” —Marx, TSV 1:403-4.
SERVICE INDUSTRY
That part of the economy which provides services rather than producing articles for sale.
See also:
PETTY’S LAW.
SHORT SELLING
Selling a financial asset such as a share of stock, or some uniform commodity, which the
seller does not actually own, but which he or she has only borrowed for the purpose.
Speculators do this when they expect the price to decline, and therefore expect to be able
to buy back the item after that price decline. They will then pocket the difference in
the selling and buying prices, after paying a fee to the broker who loaned them the stock
or commodity. If the price of the borrowed asset rises and does not fall, the
speculator will have to buy it back at a higher price, and will therefore suffer a loss.
In brief, selling short is one of a great many methods of speculative gambling that
financial capitalists have come up with.
SISMONDI, Jean Charles Léonard Simonde de (1773-1842)
Swiss economist and historian. Considered by some to be sort of an early socialist.
Marxist attitudes towards Sismondi have varied tremendously. Lenin looked down upon him
as a vulgarizer of Ricardo. But Marx himself (in volume 3 of
TSV which was not available to Lenin at the time he made his judgments) had much more
sympathy toward Sismondi and viewed him as understanding some very fundamental points about
capitalism that Ricardo could not grasp or accept:
“Sismondi is profoundly conscious of the contradictions in capitalist production; he is aware that, on the one hand, its forms—its production relations—stimulate unrestrained development of the productive forces and of wealth; and that, on the other hand, these relations are conditional, that their contradictions of use-value and exchange-value, commodity and money, purchase and sale, production and consumption, capital and wage-labor, etc., assume ever greater dimensions as productive power develops. He is particularly aware of the fundamental contradiction: on the one hand, unrestricted development of the productive forces and increase of wealth which, at the same time, consists of commodities and must be turned into cash; on the other hand, the system is based on the fact that the mass of producers is restricted to the necessaries. Hence, according to Sismondi, crises are not accidental, as Ricardo maintains, but essential outbreaks—occuring on a large scale and at definite periods—of the immanent contradictions.” —Marx, TSV, 3:56.
Marx does go on to say that Sismondi “wavers constantly” on many issues, and that his ideas are anything but well-worked out. “He [Sismondi] forcefully criticizes the contradictions of bourgeois production but does not understand them, and consequently does not understand the process whereby they can be resolved.” [Ibid.] Nevertheless, Marx later says that “Sismondi was epoch-making in political economy because he had an inkling of this contradiction” (the profound difference between Labor and Capital in the capitalist production process), that Ricardo could not understand. [TSV, 3:259.]
SKEPTICISM
1. Questioning, or caution, in accepting things as certainly true.
2. The view that human beings can attain no certain knowledge of the world; i.e.,
philosophical or epistemological agnosticism.
Sense #1 is clearly rational and scientific,
but sense #2 carries things to a ridiculous extreme.
For an essay discussing this matter in more
depth, see: “Do We Know For Certain that the Earth Goes Around the Sun?” at:
http://www.massline.org/Philosophy/ScottH/certain.htm.
SLAM [Student Liberation Action Movement]
This was a multiracial radical student organization based in colleges in New York City from
1996 to 2004, especially Hunter College in Manhattan.
In early 1995 the City University of
New York (CUNY) announced a major tuition increase and threatened to end (and later did end)
the policy of open admissions, which had been won through earlier student stuggles in 1969.
In response the students, under the leadership of an ad hoc coalition, organized a protest
of 20,000 people which surrounded City Hall. This demonstration was attacked by the police,
but the coalition continued and in 1996 transformed itself into the Student Liberation Action
Movement. The group spread to CUNY colleges in all parts of New York City, and worked to
construct a “left culture” among students. But over time the movement gradually lost force,
and SLAM was disbanded in 2004. It did, however, leave a powerful imprint upon the many
college students involved.
See also:
http://SLAMherstory.wordpress.com
for an oral history project by many of the women students involved in SLAM.
SLAVE SOCIETY
The first form of class society, based on private ownership of property and
the outright ownership and exploitation of individuals of one class (the slaves) by
individuals (or groups of individuals) of another class (the slave owners). Slave society
developed out of primitive communal society, and was replaced by
feudalism (though the existence of some
chattel slavery continued to exist well into the
capitalist era and even still continues today, though nowhere is it the dominant form of
exploitation any more. Sometimes people being held in slave conditions (often as prostitutes)
are even found in advanced capitalist countries like the United States.
SMITH, Adam (1723-1790)
The most important classical political economist before Ricardo.
He gave classical bourgeois political economy its developed form.
SOCIAL CONSCIOUSNESS
The sum total of all the acquired ideas, opinions, views, concepts, knowledge,
theories, dispositions, feelings, moods, abilities, skills, arts, practices, habits,
customs and traditions that exist among the individuals in a society and which reflect
the social being of its members (the material conditions of their lives).
SOCIAL CONTRACT
An idealist theory in which society, law and morality are the result of either a
conscious or implicit “contract” concluded among the people, or between the people and
the state. The idea is that humans have agreed to give up some of their personal freedoms
in exchange for a stable and secure political existence. This doctrine is historically
incorrect, in that (among other reasons) it supposes that human society existed in a
state of complete anarchy and bestiality (or alternately idyllic freedom according to
Rousseau) until the “contract” was concluded. It is a crude, early attempt to understand
how slave, feudal and bourgeois society could have developed. The view arose in antiquity
but received its greatest development with the rising bourgeoisie in
Hobbes, Locke and
Rousseau.
SOCIAL DARWINISM
The theory that the struggle for existence and natural selection govern social
development. It is an invalid extension of Darwin’s theory of biological evolution to
society. Its most famous exponent was Herbert Spencer, but in
various forms it is still quite popular in bourgeois circles.
SOCIAL DEMOCRACY
1. A form of the liberal capitalist welfare state mascarading as genuine socialism.
2. Political parties and movements which have this reformist accomodation with capitalism
as their highest goal.
See also:
COMMUNISM—Aims
Of
SOCIAL ORGANIZATION
See:
PRIMITIVE SOCIAL
ORGANIZATION, and
SOCIOECONOMIC FORMATION
SOCIALISM (Socialist Society)
An intermediate and transitional form of society between
capitalism and communism,
characterized in its economic aspect by the principle “From each according to his ability,
to each according to his work,” and characterized in its political aspect by the genuine
control and rule of society by the revolutionary proletariat and its party or parties.
Socialism is still a form of class society,
where class struggle still exists, and bourgeois and proletarian ideology and tendencies
still do battle. The ruling class in a genuine socialist society is the proletariat. But
many countries call (or have called) themselves socialist even though the proletariat
either never had power, or else no longer has power, and where society is not (or is no
longer) advancing towards communism (e.g., China after Mao’s death in 1976).
SOCIALLY NECESSARY LABOR TIME
[To be added...]
SOCIOBIOLOGY
[To be added...]
SOCIOECONOMIC FORMATION
One of the following stages in the development of society:
primitive communalism (or primitive communism);
slave society; feudalism;
capitalism; socialism; and
communism. Except for the first and the last of these, all
are class societies. Slave society, feudalism and capitalism all rest upon the exploitation
of one class by another, though this is somewhat hidden from view under capitalism.
These historical stages have been identified
primarily through the study of European history, and sometimes variations are hypothesized
for other areas, such as the Asiatic mode of
production which Marx talked about at times in his writings. It is more common these
days to view the “Asiatic mode of production” as a variety of feudalism.
SOCRATES (469-399 BCE)
[To be added...]
See also:
Philosophical doggerel
about Socrates.
SOLIPSISM
The crazy idealist view that there is only one thinker in the world, me!, and
that everyone and everything else is a figment of my imagination. It is doubtful if anyone
has ever taken this view seriously, but bourgeois philosophers talk about it a lot since
many of them seem to think it is difficult or impossible to refute the notion!
See also:
Philosophical doggerel
on the topic.
SOUL
[In religion:] An imagined immaterial essence of a human being which God supposedly
“puts into” the body at conception or birth (or sometime in between!), and which “leaves”
the body at death to go to heaven or hell or some other “place”. It is hard for a
materialist not to simply guffaw at such a primitive, absurd and unscientific notion.
[In wider use:] Because of humanity’s religious past, the word ‘soul’ is also used
even by non-religious people, but in more rational (if still somewhat poetic) ways, as
in describing the essential aspect or nature of something as its “soul”. Example: “Her
hard work and dedication make her the soul of the strike support committee.”
See also:
SPIRIT.
SOVIET UNION
[To be added...]
SOVIET UNION — Revisionist Seizure of Power In
[To be added...]
See also:
PATERNALISM.
SOVIETS (Councils)
The word ‘soviet’ means “council” in Russian. During the 1905 Revolution councils,
or Soviets, were first formed in a major way by the workers, peasants and soldiers
to represent their revolutionary interests. After the defeat of the 1905 Revolution these
Soviets mostly ceased functioning. But with the overthrow of the Tsar in the
February Revolution, they sprang suddenly back
into existence as an even greater force. During the course of 1917 they settled down into
being the primary representatives of the workers in their day-to-day struggles against the
capitalists, of the peasants against the landlords, of the ordinary soldiers against the
officer corps, and of all the masses against the flaky bourgeois Provisional Government.
Lenin understood the nature of the situation, that despite the current practice of the
Soviets as reformist or union-type organizations, they in effect formed a dual power along
with the formal Russian government. He further recognized that because of this, and because
the workers, peasants and soldiers viewed the Soviets as their own organizations which
truly did represent their interests (unlike the government), that an insurrection could be
led with a central slogan being “All power to the Soviets!” And, of course, Lenin proved
to be correct in his assessment.
The strategy of working toward the formation
of “soviets” or councils of workers in other countries as a step toward revolution has so
far not been successful, though it was widely attempted—especially in the first decades
after the Bolshevik Revolution. However, in the
advanced capitalist world no other strategy has worked so far either, and it is still quite
possible that something like workers’ councils will once again prove quite useful in
promoting revolution.
SPENCER, Herbert (1820-1903)
English philosopher and sociologist, and one of the founders of
positivism. [More to be added.]
See also:
SOCIAL DARWINISM.
SPINOZA, Baruch [or Benedict] (1632-1677)
Dutch semi-materialist philosopher. Spinoza held that morality is based in human
nature. He defined ‘good’ in various ways, as that which benefits the individual, as
that which brings pleasure, and so forth. Although his ethical theory was not completely
consistent and coherent, and certainly included idealistic elements, it represented a
tremendous advance at the time, and fostered naturalistic and materialistic thinking
in ethics and in philosophy in general.
SPIRIT
[To be added...]
SPLIT-CYCLE THEORY
The theory that in the imperialist era the capitalist industrial
cycle has “split in two”, i.e., into two separate (though connected) cycles with differing
periods. The short-term cycle, which like the industrial cycle in the pre-monopoly era still
usually lasts from 5 to 10 years, leads to recessions, but most
of these tend to be mild and rather easily dealt with through government actions (such as by
lowering the prevailing bank interest rates, lowering taxes, increasing
Keynesian deficit financing for government expenditures,
and the like). The long-term cycle, which is of much more irregular duration, comes to a head
when government measures can no longer “short-circuit” the developing economic contradictions
which have led to a recession, and therefore which continue to develop into an all out
depression. These depressions can only be ended through the
massive destruction of the excess capital that has built up since the previous depression.
For an elaboration of this theory see “Chapter
5: The Industrial Cycle Has Split In Two!” of my work in progress, An Introduction to
Capitalist Economic Crises at:
http://www.massline.org/PolitEcon/crises/Crises05.htm . —S.H.
STAGFLATION
The combination of economic stagnation (see below) and inflation
at the same time. According to bourgeois economics this was supposed to be impossible, but
when it first reared its ugly head in the U.S. in the late 1970s and 1980s they were forced
to admit that it could indeed happen, though they still could not explain why.
From a Marxist standpoint the explanation
for stagflation poses no problems: the stagnation aspect is simply an early sign of a
developing overproduction crisis, and inflation
is just a sign that the government is expanding the currency too fast (because of excessive
government budget deficits usually). While it is true that massive
Keynesian budget deficits can forestall
stagnation or recession (for a while!), lesser bouts of deficit financing may only slightly
mitigate the stagnation/recession while at the same time causing inflation.
STAGNATION (Economic)
The failure of an economy to grow, or for it only to grow at a very slow pace. This is
often an early indicator of a developing overproduction
crisis that is only being kept somewhat in check for a time through the expansion of
government or consumer debt but on an insufficient scale to create a more solid rate of
growth for the economy.
See also:
Paul Sweezy.
STALIN, Joseph [Iosif Vissarionovich Dzhugashvili] (1879-1953)
[To be added... ] (See also below.)
STALIN — Errors and Crimes Of
[To be added... ]
See also:
PATERNALISM.
STATE, The
[In Marxist usage:] The primary instrument of political power in class society, consisting
of organs of administration (government departments), and of force (army and police). There
are also usually auxillary organs (legislatures or parliaments, and courts of law) which
exist both to resolve conflicts within the ruling class and to lend the appearance of
fairness and “complete democracy” to the state. The state is thus a mechanism for class
rule, the embodiment of the dictatorship of a particular class, no matter how camouflaged
it may be.
STATE, The Bourgeois
The bourgeois State is the organ of power and administration which exercises the dictatorship
of the bourgeoisie (or capitalist class) over all other classes, and especially over the
proletariat (working class).
“The executive of the modern State is but a committee for managing the common affairs of the whole bourgeoisie.” —Marx & Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848), Ch. I: MECW 6:486.
STATE CAPITALISM
1. The form of capitalism in which the capitalists own the
means of production (factories, machinery, etc.) collectively and as a class, rather
than individually or in small associations (partnerships, corporations, etc.). The Soviet
Union was the prime example after the restoration of capitalism there in the mid 1950s and
until its collapse in late 1991. It seems fair to conclude these days that state capitalism
is unstable and tends to decay back into more traditional forms of monopoly capitalism.
2. [As used by various other left theorists:] Western-style monopoly capitalism, or specific
periods of it during which the state plays a more prominent role than other periods. The
bourgeois state does play a much increased role in the control and direction of capitalism in
the imperialist or monopoly capitalist era (as compared to earlier capitalism); and since the
1930s the role of the state has been further increased in monopoly capitalism. But this state
role is still qualitatively much less than it was in the Soviet Union in the revisionist era
and it is incorrect and confusing to call any period of Western-style monopoly capitalism by
the name “state capitalism” or “state monopoly capitalism”.
STEVENSON, Charles
Positivist philosopher specializing in ethics. [More to be added...]
STOICISM
[To be added...]
See also:
Philosophical doggerel about
Stoicism.
STRATEGY AND TACTICS
[To be added... ]
See also:
OCTOBER ROAD.
STRUGGLE — CRITICISM — TRANSFORMATION
A policy stage during the Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution
promoted by Mao and his followers, starting in 1968. As explained by Mao:
“Struggle-criticism-transformation in a factory, on the whole, goes through the following stages: establishing a three-in-one revolutionary committee; carrying out mass criticism and repudiation; purifying the class ranks; consolidating the Party organization; and simplifying the administrative structure, changing irrational rules and regulations and sending office workers to the workshops.” —Mao, quoted in “Unprecedentedly Excellent Situation in China’s Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution”, Peking Review, #44, Nov. 1, 1968, p. 12.
SUBJECTIVE IDEALISM
The extreme form of philosophical idealism which claims that
everything, including material objects, exists only because they are collections of sensations
or “ideas” in someone’s mind, or else in the mind of God. A prominent champion of this bizarre
view was Bishop Berkeley.
SUB-PRIME MORTGAGE
A mortgage issued to someone with a fairly poor credit rating.
Why would a bank or other financial
institution make such a loan which stands a high likelihood of default? First of all, they
usually charge a higher interest rate and a larger up-front fee. However, one of the main
reasons that sub-prime mortgages became so common in the first decade of the 21st
century is that the issuers of the mortgage (the banks, etc.) found ways to “securitize” it,
i.e. to repackage the mortgage in small slices and sell them to other investors in a form where
their stupidity was not obvious. (See Collateralized Debt Obligation.)
Thus the bank issuing the mortgage would not suffer even if the mortgage did go into
default; that would only harm the suckers who bought the “sliced-and-diced” securities.
Ironically, many of the issuers of CDOs seem to have got caught up in the marketing hype they
generated to sell these wonderful new investments, forgot just what they were up to, and often
kept or invested in these securitized bad mortgages themselves! Thus they also got caught in
this trap of their own making.
SUN SPOT THEORY (Of Economic Crises)
A theory originated by the bourgeois economist William Stanley Jevons
(1835-82) which claims that the periodic prominence of dark spots on the surface of the sun is
responsible for economic crises in the capitalist economies on earth. Though erroneous, this is
not quite as ridiculous as it initally sounds! The sun goes through a 11-year cycle of varying
numbers of sun spots, from almost none, to a great many, and back to almost none. These spots
are actually plasma storms, and when they are abundant large quantities of charged particles
are spewed off into space, some of which reach the earth and cause effects here, including the
auroras and interruptions to radio communications. It is possible that there may also be small
changes to crop yields because of atmospheric and weather changes, and this was the basis for
Jevons’ theory. However, such crop changes are very small—if they occur at all. Moreover,
neither the peaks nor valleys of the 11-year cycle of sun spots correlate well with the
varying periods of 5 to 10 years in the standard industrial cycle.
Clearly the bourgeois economists come up with
rather silly theories like this, which try to explain economic crises by “exogenous” factors
(i.e., factors external to the capitalist system), because they simply cannot accept that
capitalism itself has any internal flaw which leads to such crises, despite the fact that
Marx explained in detail how this occurs.
SUPERSTRUCTURE
See: BASE and SUPERSTRUCTURE
SUPPLY AND DEMAND
[To be added...]
SURPLUS VALUE
“The action of labor-power ... not only reproduces its own value, but produces value over
and above it. This surplus-value is the difference between the value of the product and the
value of the elements consumed in the formation of that product, in other words, of the
means of production and the labour-power.” —Marx, Capital, vol. I, ch. VIII: (International,
p. 208; Penguin, p. 317.) Or, roughly equivalent, surplus value is the value of the commodities
produced by the workers after deducting their wages, the cost of raw materials and the overhead.
[To lay bare the essential character of capitalist production:] “This was done by the discovery of surplus-value. It was shown that the appropriation of unpaid labor is the bais of the capitalist mode of production and of the exploitation of the worker that occurs under it; that even if the capitalist buys the labor-power of his laborer at its full value as a commodity on the market, he yet extracts more value from it than he paid for; and that in the ultimate analysis this surplus-value forms those sums of value from which are heaped up the constantly increasing masses of capital in the hands of the possessing classes. The genesis of capitalist production and the production of capital were both explained.” —Engels, Anti-Dühring (1878), MECW 25:27.
SWEEZY, Paul Malor (1910-2004)
Paul Sweezy was an influential American Marxist political economist and in 1949 the co-founder
(along with the Marxist historian, Leo Huberman) of the important publication for the American
Left, Monthly Review. Along with Paul Baran and Harry
Magdoff he formed the core of the “Monthly Review school” of Marxist political economy centered
around that magazine.
Sweezy was born in New York City, the son of a
bank executive. He attended an elite prep school, Phillips Exeter Academy and then Harvard
University where he graduated in 1931. He then spent a year at the London School of Economics
where he was first exposed in a serious way to Marxist economic ideas. He returned to Harvard as
a graduate student, where one of his professors was Joseph Schumpeter.
He received his doctorate in 1937, and then began teaching economics at Harvard. During World
War II he was a member of the research and analysis division of the Office of Strategic Services
(forerunner to the CIA), where one of his jobs was in effect to spy on the British
government! (U.S. imperialism was already thinking very seriously about the contention among
the victors in the war for the control of the world that would ensue after it ended.)
In 1942 Sweezy published one of his most
important books, The Theory of Capitalist Development, which summarized Marxist economic
ideas (though with a partially Keynesian interpretation), and argued for what its opponents
call an “underconsumptionist” theory of capitalist
economic crises. This was one of the first books in English to extensively deal with a number
of important topics in Marxist political economy, including the
“transformation problem”.
In 1966 there appeared another important book,
Monopoly Capital, by Sweezy and Paul Baran. This
put forth the theory that modern monopoly capitalism is inherently prone to
stagnation. However, a lot of the argument in that book is actually
about how the capitalists can overcome (at least to a large degree and for a long time)
this tendency. The authors say this can be done through massive corporate waste, through
enormously intensified marketing, through a special focus on military production for the
government, through innovation and new industries, and through the massive build-up of debt of
all kinds (consumer, business and government debt). That last point is the most central, and
does not receive sufficient emphasis in the book. Moreover, it seems to me that their position
here is somewhat between that of Keynes and Marx. Sweezy and Baran seemed to grant the
capitalists too much in the way of an ability to permanently forestall another great depression,
and even—it seems at times—to grant them too much ability to forestall the lesser difficulty of
“stagnation” that they talked about. That is, they did not seem to fully understand that
Keynesian deficits, consumer debt, etc., themselves have definite limits and must fail
in the end, and they may not have realized just how serious this would become for capitalism.
Today, in early 2009, we are already getting a glimmer of the fact that for the capitalists,
the real problem is not just a “tendency toward stagnation”, but something far, far worse: the
inevitability of a prolonged, intractable economic depression.
Politically, Sweezy and Magdoff (who became
co-editor of Monthly Review after Huberman’s death) generally improved their outlook
over time. While initially enamored by Fidel Castro and the Cuban Revolution, they later
developed a more cautious attitude. As time went on they became more appreciative of Mao and
the great Chinese Revolution. However, like most Marxists of their generation they found it
hard to completely break with the triumphant revisionism of the Soviet Union. Sweezy was one
of those who used to talk about “actually existing
socialism” in the USSR, meaning that with all its actual faults, it should still be viewed
as “socialism”. (At least from the mid-1950s on this was definitely not the case!)
The articles that Sweezy and Magdoff themselves
wrote for MR were in general much better than many of the articles they accepted for
the magazine as its editors. While some of those articles were also quite good, there were also
quite a number of others supporting revisionist “Euro-Communism”, reformist politics, and the
like. Late in his life Sweezy admitted that their magazine should also have played a much
greater role in helping to create a new revolutionary proletarian party in the U.S. Interestingly,
after Sweezy and Magdoff died, and under its new editor, John Bellamy Foster, MR has
further improved, and now has a stronger Maoist flavor to it.
See also:
Monopoly Capital (the book).
Glossary Home Page and Letter Index